The
trustbusters' new tools
Activist competition policy is
back in style. Thank big changes in economic thinking
ANY day now,
For most of this century,
``industrial organisation''-the branch of economics that studies
competition-has been an intellectual backwater. But now, as trustbusters weigh
an unprecedented number of mergers (see chart) and all sorts of novel business
arrangements that would reshape industries from publishing to defence and
accounting to aviation, the intellectual tide has turned. The economic ideas of
the 1970s and 1980s argued overwhelmingly that government activism in
competition was often unwarranted and counterproductive. Now they are giving
way to new thinking that justifies tougher antitrust enforcement. That
competition authorities seem to be casting a more sceptical eye is partly
thanks to these fresh ideas.
Surprisingly perhaps, the
controversies surrounding Microsoft plough little new intellectual ground.
Although technophiles are prone to assert that advanced technology has changed
everything, few new antritrust problems are posed by Microsoft's purported
sins, which involve mostly predation against competitors in a supposed effort
to monopolise parts of the software industry. If advanced technology has
changed competition policy, it is for another reason entirely: that computers
have greatly enhanced economists' ability to crunch numbers and model
behaviour. The pages that follow describe these new techniques and the thinking
that lies behind them.
Never mind the market
No matter the issue at
hand, economists, lawyers and judges are wont to begin their analysis of
competition by asking a single question: what market are we worried about? Yet,
in one of the most startling developments in industrial organisation,
economists have now concluded that ``the market'' does not necessarily matter.
Consider the most basic
task of trust-busters: to keep any firm from exercising ``market power'', the
ability to set prices higher than competition would allow. In the past,
economists sought to measure market power with the Herfindahl-Hirschman Index,
which is determined by adding the squares of the market shares of all firms
involved. If the Herfindahl is low, there are many competitors and exercising
market power should be hard; a high Herfindahl, on the other hand, was thought
to warn of a concentrated market in which price rises are easier to sustain.
The Herfindahl's great
virtue is its simplicity. But that virtue masks two shortcomings. First, there
is often no clear way to define what market is at stake. In the current
investigation of the proposed alliance between British Airways and American
Airlines, for example, the carriers assert that the relevant market is travel
between the
Frustration with the
Herfindahl's failings has led economists in a different direction. Instead of
calculating market shares, they seek to gauge if an arrangement such as a
merger will drive prices higher than they would be otherwise. According to
Jerry Hausman, an economist at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology,
economists can actually model oligopolistic behaviour and predict what will
happen if the merger goes ahead. This has become possible with the spread of
two technologies during the past decade: desktop computers with extraordinary
number-crunching power and the scanners used at retailers' check-outs.
These techniques were first
applied in 1995, when Interstate Bakeries,
Thousands of equations
later, economists from the Department of Justice concluded that the price of
Interstate's sliced white breads strongly affected sales of Continental's
Wonder bread, and vice versa, but made little difference to sales of other
white breads or other varieties, such as rye. Having shown that each company's
brands were the main restraint on the other's prices, the authorities moved to
block the merger. In the end Interstate met their objections by selling some of
its brands and bakeries.
The empirical analysis went
still further with last year's proposed merger of Staples and Office Depot, two
chains of office-supply ``superstores' ' in
Some practitioners, such as
Greg Werden of the Department of Justice, suggest that when scanner data or
similar information is available, defining a market need no longer be part of
antitrust analysis. The courts have yet to accept that view. But this
econometric approach has greatly influenced
That central concern is the
legacy of the academics from the
Incontestable
The
A decade ago, under
To understand
contestability, first recall that monopolies are undesirable because they can
restrict output and raise prices so as to increase their own profitability at
the expense of consumers. But economists showed in the early 1980s that raising
prices is not always in a monopolist' s interest,
because it may attract other firms to enter the market. If entry is easy and
costless-in other words, if the market is ``contestable' '-a sensible
monopolist will forestall competition by setting prices as if it were operating
in a competitive market, and there will be no economic harm.
Contestability theory was
conceived with telecoms in mind-indeed much of the research was sponsored by
American Telephone & Telegraph (AT&T), then fighting attempts to
dismantle its national telephone monopoly. But the idea was soon applied to
other industries, notably aviation. Go ahead and deregulate routes and fares,
the theory taught, because even if only one airline flies on a route, it will
keep fares low to deter rivals. Contestability offered a rationale for easing
anti- monopoly rules in both
In the enthusiasm, however,
one condition was forgotten. For a market to be fully contestable, firms must
be able to avoid large sunk costs. The newcomer must be able to make a one-way
bet, winning if profits are good, but losing nothing if it should decide to
retreat.
The real world is not like
that. A bakery would have to advertise its brand in a new market-an investment
that would be wasted were it to back away. A new office-supply chain would have
to continue paying rent even if it were to close its shops. As a firm weighs
whether to sink costs, it knows that the high profits that look so enticing now
will shrink with competition. And so, taken to its conclusion, contestability
theory leads to an arresting result: the greater the sunk costs, the less the incentive for new firms to compete against an incumbent,
which therefore can restrict output and raise prices.
The belief that firms would
find clever ways to hinder competition was one of the original motives for
anti-monopoly laws. This was a threat that the
Of Bork and brokers
Mr Bork says his views have
not changed-even though he is now an adviser to Netscape, a software firm that
has accused Microsoft of predatory behaviour. What has
changed is the sorts of models game theorists employ, which are far richer and
more complex than those used two decades ago. ``The
How, for example, can
stockbrokers maintain wide spreads between the price they pay for shares and
the price at which they sell them, as occurred until recently on America's
NASDAQ stockmarket? Simple game theory suggests that this kind of behaviour
will not persist, because each broker will narrow his spread in anticipation of
another firm doing so first. But as Derek Morris, head of
Predatory behaviour also
looks less innocent through the lens of sophisticated game theory. Following
the
This reasoning is
correct-in some cases. Enforcers ``really do have to worry about scaring off
real competition,'' says Jonathan Baker, chief economist at the FTC. However,
by simulating complex interactions among firms, economists are able to show
that predatory pricing may be highly profitable. Authorities in both
In addition, the academics
of the
` Raising rivals' costs.
When
`
Reducing rivals' revenues. A different sort of predation was behind a Microsoft
strategy that obliged computer makers to pay it a royalty on each machine they
sold, whether or not it carried Microsoft's software. Frederick Warren-Boulton,
a Washington-based economist and former Justice Department official, labels
this a ``tax'' on competitors: customers will be unwilling to pay much for
other firms' software, as they must already pay for Microsoft's. Microsoft
changed its policy in 1995, but a current court case, dealing with its efforts
to undercut Netscape by giving away its Internet browser, raises similar
issues. ``This is a class of problem that has not been analysed before,'' Mr
Warren-Boulton says.
`
Connected markets.
The
No monopoly of wisdom
None of these types of
predation, it is worth pointing out, can succeed in a highly competitive
environment of the kind the
Economists themselves, of
course, are no less entrepreneurial than other folk. Given prompting, they will
happly tout the novelty of their work. So it is perhaps inevitable that some of
the ideas now being touted as revolutionary insights may be less startling or
useful than advertised.
One example is network
effects. The notion is that some businesses- Internet access, credit cards and
computer software, to name three- differ fundamentally from other economic
activities because the desire for compatibility makes certain forms of
competition impractical or even unwanted. Although this sounds dramatic, the
consequences for policy are fairly minor and involve old-fashioned regulation.
The question of how to keep the owner of an ``essential facility'', such as a
credit-card approval network, from exploiting its monopoly power is an old one;
the European Union's examination of competition in Internet access raises
questions similar to the investigation that led to the break up of AT&T by
the American authorities.
The new approach to
competition by no means heralds a return to the pre-Chicago days when bigness
itself was deemed to be an evil. Indeed, it explicitly emphasises market power
rather than size, which was anyway only ever an unsatisfactory proxy. Nor does
the new approach mean that trustbusters will bring more cases. ``You still need
to prove something bad is happening and get customers to complain about it,''
says Robert Litan, a former antitrust official now with the Brookings
Institution in Washington. ``You can't make an antitrust case out of fancy
economic theories.'' But the fancy theories will, without doubt, motivate
enforcers to investigate business behaviour that hitherto would have raised no
eyebrows. They will come to understand new ways in which businesses acquire
excessive market power. Consumers should be grateful.
Author
not available, The trustbusters' new tools. Vol. 347, The Economist,
eLibrary is
a service of Infonautics Corporation. Copyright © 2001.
All rights reserved.